Some important posts on Wages, Jobs, and The Fed | Economics on Blog#42

Some important posts on Wages, Jobs, and The Fed

I am re-posting three of Jared Bernstein’s recent posts on wages, jobs, and the Fed, beginning with some comments from me, for readers to mull over as they work through Jared’s writings. I also highly recommend reading Jared’s Washington Post piece on Targets vs. ceilings at the Federal Reserve.

Food and fuel prices are not included in the inflation measures (CPI and CPE) because they’re thought to be volatile. In a 2004 education paper entitled ‘What is “core inflation,” and why do economists use it instead of overall or general inflation to track changes in the overall price level?‘, the San Francisco Fed explains why food and gas are excluded from CPI:

“The question of the correct way to measure inflation is an important one. Price stability over time, along with “maximum” sustainable economic output and employment, are the Federal Reserve’s primary goals in making monetary policy. The maintenance of price stability—avoiding high inflation rates or deflation over time—is important because fluctuating prices distort the economy’s price signals and can result in the misallocation of resources. 1

The Federal Reserve carefully reviews and analyzes the available inflation measures to monitor how well it is achieving its price stability goal. One common way economists use inflation data is by looking at “core inflation,” which is generally defined as a chosen measure of inflation (e.g., the Consumer Price Index or CPI, the Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index or PCEPI, or the Gross Domestic Product Deflator) that excludes the more volatile categories of food and energy prices.

Why are food and energy prices typically more volatile than other prices?

To understand why the categories of food and energy are more sensitive to price changes, consider environmental factors that can ravage a year’s crops, or fluctuations in the oil supply from the OPEC cartel. Each is an example of a supply shock that may affect the prices for that product. However, although the prices of those goods may frequently increase or decrease at rapid rates, the price disturbances may not be related to a trend change in the economy’s overall price level. Instead, changes in food and energy prices often are more likely related to temporary factors that may reverse themselves later.”

Over the last seven years gas prices certainly have been volatile, having gone up very high and, of late, sunk relatively low. But the other two main expenditure in a consumer’s budget, housing and food, have gone up quite sharply and steadily over the same period of time, as salaries have stagnated after an initial post-Great Recession drop. Neither has fluctuated.

Housing is now reaching crisis levels in large portions of the US, with homelessness becoming a problem among those who are employed (many at more than one job) but not able to earn enough to cover basic needs. Of late, as more jobs have been filled, there has been some increase in wages, but not enough to keep up with the rise in housing costs. Given the qualitative nature of these new jobs, however, and as Jared points out, the rise in pay doesn’t quite make a difference in terms of inflation. Inequality is far too wide and the rise too modest, hence, the rise of a new social class called the “precariat” (see my series of articles).

Rather than worry about inflation, we should be worrying about secular stagnation. As defined by the Financial Times’ lexicon, here is an explanation of secular stagnation:

“Secular stagnation is a condition of negligible or no economic growth in a market-based economy. When per capita income stays at relatively high levels,  the percentage of savings is likely to start exceeding the percentage of longer-term investments in, for example, infrastructure and education, that are necessary to sustain future economic growth. The absence of such investments (and consequently of the economic growth) leads to declining levels of per capita income (and consequently of per capita savings). With the reduced percentage savings rate converging with the reduced investment rate, economic growth comes to a standstill – ie, it stagnates. In a free economy, consumers anticipating secular stagnation, might transfer their savings to more attractive-looking foreign countries. This would lead to a devaluation of their domestic currency, which would potentially boost their exports, assuming that the country did have goods or services that could be exported.

Persistent low growth, especially in Europe, has been attributed by some to secular stagnation initiated by stronger European economies, such as Germany, in the past few years.”

My observations have direct bearing on the current rethinking of what the Fed’s targets should be in this new post-recession economy, both for inflation (that includes rises in wages and prices) and what should be considered full employment, given the nature of the jobs that are being added, and their ability to sustain and increase demand in a fashion that lends itself to sustained growth and a healthy economy.

What was true in terms of calculating the CPI up until 2008, may not longer be true in the post-Great Recession from 2010 to the present-day, and for as long as austerity politics, and not the underlying economics, dictate the growth of our economy, the rules by which CPI is measured should be adapted for the political realities we are living, and not the pre-2008 status quo ante.


Notice to readers: I urgently need your help. Please click here for a personal message.


Rebalancing factor shares: Another (great) source of non-inflationary wage growth

March 25th, 2016

by Jared Bernstein

As Dean Baker pointed out to me this AM, the labor share of national income is slowly gaining back some of its losses, as shown in the figure below (see circled part at end). This is a good thing, and should, to some extent, reduce inequality by shifting some of the growth from profits into paychecks.

Since there’s a lot of inequality within labor’s share of national income, this development won’t reduce inequality that much. That is, income growth is still disproportionately going to higher paychecks, as Elise Gould shows here. But the shift you see below is a distributionally positive development, and evidence that the tight job market is delivering a bit more bargaining power to workers (these shares don’t sum to 100 percent because they leave out proprietors’ incomes, as it’s hard to break that down between wages and profits).

Source: NIPA tbl 1.12

Source: NIPA tbl 1.12

My point here, however, is a bit different, and it’s one targeted at the Federal Reserve. Nor is my point simply to badger them not to raise rates pre-emptively, potentially slowing the progress you see in the figure.

Um…well, maybe it kinda is, but with a bit of the sort of math they enjoy over there.

Chair Yellen has consistently maintained that as long as nominal wages grow no faster than the Fed’s inflation target of 2 percent plus productivity growth, which is running at (a truly yucky) 1 percent these days, wages can grow 3 percent without generating inflationary pressures.

In other words, in Fed land non-inflationary wage growth (NIWG) = i + p, where i is the inflation target and p is productivity growth. When last seen, wages were growing between 2-2.5 percent, so steady as she goes, based on this rule.

But based on the figure above, I’d like to add an x-factor to that above equation, such that:

NIWG = i + p + x

…where x represents the pace at which the gap you see above is closing. That is, there’s another component to NIWG: rebalancing labor’s share of national income. Usefully, the math of how that gap closes reduces to how much faster average compensation is growing compared to productivity (as the gap opened up post-2000, average comp growth consistently outpaced productivity).

In other words, if you’d like to see “factor shares”—the shares of income going to capital and labor—rebalance, then you want to allow for another source of non-inflationary wage growth: redistribution from profits to wages.

Thankfully, economist Josh Bivens, who wrote about all of the above for CBPPs full employment project, figured out that if x were, say 1 percent—i.e., if average compensation grew 1 percent faster than productivity growth—it would take over eight years for the gap to get back to its pre-recession level.

More to the point, it would lead the Fed to tolerate 4 percent versus 3 percent wage growth.

I don’t mean to push the precision of any of this too far. For one, p is, as noted, pretty depressed right now, and it could accelerate, providing more oxygen for NIWG. More importantly, the evidence of wage growth bleeding into price growth has been pretty hard to come by in recent years, so I wouldn’t put a ton of weight on the basic model in the first place.

My only point is that if, like the Fed, this is the model you’ve kind of got in your head, then there’s another factor—another source of non-inflationary wage growth—that you should seriously consider.

***Reprinted with the permission of Jared Bernstein


Why hitting a target sometimes means missing a target

March 17th, 2016

by Jared Bernstein

Given the Fed’s persistent record of undershooting their inflation target, I and others argue that as there’s some tentative evidence of inflation firming up a bit, hitting the target on average means overshooting for awhile. The key point is that their 2 percent target is a target, not a ceiling. Over at WaPo.

BTW, some may raise an objection to this line of reasoning that at her presser yesterday, Chair Yellen stated that the interest-rate-setting committee is “not trying to engineer an overshoot of inflation, not to compensate for past undershoots.”

But the question is not what they’re “trying to engineer” as much as what they’ll tolerate. Will they accommodate core inflation above 2% or hit the brakes hard should it hit the target? The target argument, embedded, as I show, in their long-term goals, suggests such accommodation is warranted. What they actually will do, otoh, is yet to be seen.

Sources: BLS, BEA, Fed

Sources: BLS, BEA, Fed

***Reprinted with the permission of Jared Bernstein


Five simple formulas that capture today’s economic challenges and solutions.

March 21st, 2016

By Jared Bernstein

Contemporary economics is often criticized for being too mathematical. How can we really capture the complex dynamics of what’s happening in people’s economic lives with a bunch of formulas?

In fact, the point of all the math is to distill people’s complex experiences down to something we can model, understand, measure, and maybe predict. Yes, all models are wrong, in the sense that the distillation loses important nuance. But some models are useful.

With that in mind, here are five useful, simple models, all in the form of inequalities (i.e., “x is greater than y”). Each one tells you something important about the big economic problems we face today or, for the last two formulas, what we should do about them. And when I say “simple,” I mean it. It may have taken a lot of gnarly calculations to get to these formulas, but you don’t need any of that to understand and appreciate their critically important messages.

r>g

Think of this one as Piketty’s warning. It simply argues that if the return on wealth, or r, is greater than the economy’s growth rate, g, then wealth will continue to become ever more concentrated among a narrow slice of households.

To make it simple, let’s say Sally Capital gets a 3 percent return on her wealth holdings year in and year out, most of which she adds back into to her base wealth of stocks, bonds, Picassos and Stradivariuses. Meanwhile, Joe Paycheck’s income—purely from work—grows 2 percent, and he and his family don’t save (build capital) any of that; they must spend it all to survive. Add in the fact that there are a lot more Joes than Sallies, and you see the problem.

Piketty’s data show some periods when the return to wealth was lower than the growth rate (r<g), but he argues those days are behind us. Others have cast doubt on the dynamics of r>g, or at least pointed out ways in which the returns to wealth could be more diffuse (e.g., Sally bequeaths some wealth to Joe; Joe joins an ESOP), thus questioning Piketty’s warning that wealth inequality will inexorably grow.

But there is little question that wealth concentration is at historically high levels and that mechanisms by which capital ownership could be diffused—like more progressive inheritance taxation or a financial transaction tax—are politically out of favor, particularly in the U.S. Meanwhile, the Joe Paycheck scenario cited above—2 percent growth—is actually better than the experience of too many working households. Thus, we should take Piketty’s warning seriously.

S>I

Think of this one as Bernanke’s imbalance, though he calls it the “savings glut” (S is savings, I is investment). Larry Summers’ “secular stagnation” concerns offer a similar, though somewhat more narrow, version. For the record, I think this one is really serious (I mean, they’re all really serious, but relative to r>g, S>I is underappreciated).

If you suffered through econ 101, you might get tripped up by S>I, as we’re taught that what’s saved gets invested, so the correct formula should be S=I. But while that’s true for the world, it’s not true for individual countries, which can and do save more than they produce, thus running a trade surplus. Since S>I in, say, China, and S=I in the aggregate, S must be < I somewhere else, like the U.S., which runs large trade deficits. By “large,” I mean deficits averaging around -2.5 percent of GDP since the late 1970s and -4 percent since 2000, that have created a significant drag on growth. A nation can, and we have, offset this drag with other parts of GDP, but that’s led to deeply damaging bubbles, busts, and intractable recessions.

The really interesting part of the S>I problem is that, in theory, there are key mechanisms in the economy that should automatically kick in and repair the disequilibrium. The currency of the country with a trade deficit should fall relative to the currency of the surplus country, boosting the (now cheaper) exports of the former and suppressing the (now more expensive) exports of the latter. But the surplus country can jam that mechanism by manipulating the exchange rate to keep their currency cheap relative to that of their competitors.

Similarly, interest rates can fall to bring S and I back in line. But Summers and Krugman stress that when rates are already very low—like zero, which is where our central bank rate was for years until recently—the system once again gets jammed.

Central bankers, like Bernanke and Yellen, tend to discuss S>I and the jammed mechanisms just noted as “temporary headwinds” that will eventually dissipate (Summers disagrees). But while it has jumped around the globe—S>I is more a German thing right now than a China thing (Germany’s trade surplus is 8 percent of GDP!)—the S>I problem has lasted too long to warrant a “temporary” label. Ergo, doing something about it, perhaps by going after currency manipulation in trade agreements (or outside of trade agreements as a second-best approach) or otherwise pressuring large surplus countries, should be a serious response.

(Those of you still with me may note an interesting wrinkle at this point. When S>I, r tends to fall such that Piketty’s r>g may be less likely to hold. In fact, the profit share of national income has come down a bit of late relative to the wage share. But we are far from out of the inequality woods, and Piketty’s warning is still very much worth heeding.)

u>u*

Think of this one as Baker/Bernstein’s slack attack. The first “u” is the unemployment rate and “u*” is a construct called the “natural rate” of unemployment, or the lowest unemployment rate consistent with stable inflation. No one knows what u* is and it’s increasingly hard to identify, but that’s actually not a big problem for this warning, as you’ll see.

What Dean and I have shown in various writings is that for most of the past few decades—about 70 percent of the time, to be precise—u has been > than mainstream estimates of u*, meaning the job market has been slack, characterized by weak labor demand. That, in turn, has led to diminished worker bargaining power, real wage stagnation, and higher inequality.

But if u* is so hard to identify, how do we know that u is greater than it? Because, if anything, the estimates of u* are biased up, not down. Thus, our 70 percent is probably a low-ball estimate.

Back in the 1990s, for example, the experts thought u* was around 6 percent (they’ve since marked it down). So when the actual u fell below that level, they concluded the slack had been squeezed out of the job market (i.e., they thought u<u*). But, in fact, they were overestimating u*—that’s the best explanation for the fact that, when unemployment fell all the way down to 4 percent in the late 1990s, inflation failed to react as predicted, meaning it didn’t speed up. Today’s Federal Reserve has been relearning that same lesson, as they’ve continuously lowered their estimate of the “natural rate” as inflation failed to accelerate when u kept hitting it.

From the 1940s to the late 1970s, u>u* only 30 percent of the time, meaning the job market was mostly at full employment. Since then, as noted, the job market’s been slack 70 percent of the time. That’s terribly persistent slack, and a reason why getting to and staying at full employment has been such an important agenda for us and other economic progressives.

By the way, as Dean argues in this paper, one reason u>u* is that S>I (persistent trade deficits make it a lot tougher to get to full employment without inflating nasty bubbles).

These three formulas—r>g, S>I, and u>u*—are all basically bad news. They’re economic pathologies implying increasing inequality, weak demand, and slack labor markets. But despair not! These next two formulas point to an important way out of the mess implied by the first three.

g>t

Think of this one as Kogan’s cushion. In a recent paper, budget analyst Richard Kogan made a critical and underappreciated discovery: for most of the years that our country has existed (he’s got data back to 1792!), the economy’s growth rate (g again) has been greater than the rate the government has to pay to service its debt, which I call t. Kogan calls it r since it’s a rate of return, but it’s not the same r as in Piketty (which is why I’m calling it t). Piketty’s r is the return to wealth holdings; Kogan’s is the interest rate on Treasury bills. They’re related but not the same, and Kogan’s t will typically be lower than Piketty’s r, for good reasons (e.g., being such a safe lender, the U.S. government doesn’t need to pad its t with a “risk premium”).

OK, but why does this make the list? Because it means we should be far less obsessive about our deficits and debts, especially when greater public spending could alleviate some of the pathologies described above. When g>t, the economy is spinning off enough growth, and thus tax revenues, to service the debt burden without going further into debt, or risking the debt spiral you’d get if t<g. As Kogan puts it, “when economic growth rates exceed Treasury interest rates, the burden of existing debt shrinks over time.”

Since 1947, g has been > t about two-thirds of the time, by 1.3 percentage points on average. But, as Kogan stresses, CBO tends to assume that t will exceed g, which a) makes their debt forecasts too pessimistic, and b) may well be toocautious given how low interest rates have been in recent years (partially a function of S>I, btw; lots of idle capital makes for low rates, as does accommodative Fed policy). Those forecasts give rise to austere budget politics that overemphasize the importance of paying down the debt, even at the expense of critical public spending and investments.

To be clear, my “far less obsessive” point above does not mean we can ignore our public debt, and in fact, one prominent theme of my own work is that we will need more tax revenues in the future if we hope to meet the challenges and obligations faced by the public sector in a fiscally sustainable manner. But too often the prevailing, embedded assumption that g<t is used as a cudgel against government doing what it needs to do. Kogan’s work reveals this assumption to be inconsistent with the historical record.

h>0.05

Think of this one as the DeLong/Summers low-cost lunch. It’s more obscure than the others, but really very intuitive when you break it down. All they’re saying is that when the private economy is weak, government spending can be a very low-cost way to lift not just current jobs and incomes, but future growth as well. In tandem with “Kogan’s cushion,” these formulas provide an important recipe for what to do in recessions and slow-growth economies (hmmm…can anyone think of a slow-growth economy?).

The “h” stands for hysteresis, which describes the long-term damage to the economy’s growth potential when policy neglect allows depressed economies to persist over time. When that happens, the stock of capital grows more slowly and the skills of un- and underemployed workers atrophy. It may sound theoretical, but if you look at our current investment record along with our labor force participation of prime-age workers (non-retirees), you see hysteresis in action. It’s tough to get a job when you’ve been out of work for a couple of years.

So, what’s the 0.05 got to do with it? In a 2012 paper, D&S argue that when the economy’s doing poorly and interest rates are low, it is worthwhile for the government to intervene even when h is very small. They write that “…even a small amount of hysteresis—even a small shadow cast on future potential output by the cyclical downturn—means…that expansionary fiscal policy is likely to be self-financing…[or at least] highly likely to pass the sensible benefit-cost test of raising the present value of future potential output.”

Basically, given reasonable assumptions about a bunch of other moving parts, D&S find that as long as an increase in current output by a dollar raises future output by at least a nickel, the extra spending will be easily affordable. But how do we know if h<0.05?

In a follow-up paper for CBPP’s full-employment project, D&S, along with economist Larry Ball, back out a recent number for h that amounts to 0.24, multiples of the 0.05 threshold, and evidence that, at least recently, h>0.05. QED!

One reason to like all these formulas is that their policy implications are self-evident. Piketty’s warning speaks to the importance of progressive taxation and very much against the type of tax ideas proffered by today’s conservatives. Pushing back on S>I means a) going after countries that manage their currencies to maintain this imbalance and b) offsetting low I with public investment, say in physical and human capital improvements. Given Kogan’s historical finding of g>t, in tandem with h well above 0.05, such investment should be a slam dunk. Were we to go there, we’d surely be pushing back on u>u*, which would, along with making Dean and me very happy, deliver more much-needed bargaining power and wage growth to working people.

To the extent that we fail to heed these formulaic warnings and guideposts, it won’t be because the math is wrong. It won’t be because they’re too arcane. It won’t be because they don’t have solid empirical groundings. It will be because politics and power decide to ignore them.

I unfortunately don’t have a good formula for that one. But I will relentlessly fight back until reason, fairness, and equity regain their long-denied perch.


 

Message to readers:  Thanks to the generosity of readers like you, my family has averted homelessness for now. We are very grateful. We are, however, still very far from meeting our goal for the GoFundMe campaign to help save my family. Your continued support is very deeply appreciated. Thank you.


 

Related:

https://www.rimaregas.com/2016/03/the-progressive-neoliberal-split-is-over-trade-jobs-investment-a-living-wage-blog42/

 

 

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *